Substitution of the production factors in the theory of Sraffa

First insertion on Heterodoxe Gazet Sam de Wolff: 27 februari 2013

E.A. Bakkum is a blogger for the Sociaal Consultatiekantoor. He loves to reflect on the labour movement.

In a previous column it has been explained how the formation of prices is realized in the various economic paradigms. The present column is a direct continuation of that text. In an example it will be shown how the substitution of the production factors relates to the change of the production technique. The example uses the neoricardian model of Piero Sraffa. An attempt is made to connect this formalism to the neoclassical substitution of production factors.

The reader will not find the contents of this column in the introductory text books about the neoricardian paradigm1. In fact it is little more than a five-finger exercise, which is an obligatory occupation for any researcher, and which in case of the theory of Sraffa yields such rewarding results2. So although one must not expect pioneering results in this column, it is all still sufficiently interesting to publish in the Gazette.


Applications of two techniques

In order to restrict the length of the text, the mathematical and economical explanation of the model will be omitted. The reader can find her in the preceding column, just mentioned. For the sake of convenience the example is again the familiar economic system with two branches: the agriculture and the industry. The agriculture produces corn (with the bale as its unit) and the industry produces metal (with the ton as its unit). Since the theme consists of the switching of the technique, the system must allow for two techniques. Here they are indicated by α and β.

The difference of the two techniques concerns the production methods in the agriculture. In the technique α the agriculture employs the production method τ(g1) and in the technique β the production method τ(g2). In both cases the production method in the industry, called τ(m1), is identical. The technical coefficients for the three methods are summarized in the table 1. The reader can also find this table in the column about the choice of the technique in the neoricardian paradigm. Henceforth the text will regularly revert to the results of that column.

Table 1: methods per branch
(j = g or m)
agricultureindustry
τ(g1)τ(g2)τ(m1)
agj0.41670.27271.290
amj0.016670.090910.6452
aj1.6670.40913.226

In order to understand the arguments it is essential to study the properties of the two methods τ(g1) and τ(g2). The table 2 displays the differences. The method τ(g1) uses per produced bale of corn more corn and less metal than the method τ(g2). It will be shown that for normal prices the method τ(g2) requires more capital goods than the method τ(g1). The cause is the high price pm of metal in comparison with the price pg of corn.

Furthermore, it is striking that the production of a bale of corn by means of the method τ(g1) requires more labour than for the case of τ(g2). The two numbers refer to the total quantity of produced corn Qg. But it will be shown that the difference also holds for the nett product QgN. The nett product is the commonly used measure for the labour productivity. Therefore in the table 2 the labour productivity of the method τ(g2) is larger than the one of τ(g1).

Table 2: differences between the methods in the agriculture
hallmarkτ(g1)τ(g2)   hallmarkτ(g1)τ(g2)
cornmuchlittle   labourmuchlittle
metallittlemuch   nett productivitylowhigh
total capitallittlemuch      

In the column about price formation the fundamental equations for the production in the neoricardian model are given by the formulas 1 and 3. They are repeated here, without the accessory discussion about their meaning:

(1a)     QN = (I − A) · Q
(1b)     L = a · Q

For a start the set 1a-b will be explained as if for each time only one technique is available. In other words, the set refers to either the technique α (with 2×2 matrix Aα and vertical 1×2 vector aα), or the technique β (with ditto matrix Aβ and horizontal vector aβ), but not with a combination of both. The system allows for some dynamics, because the production technique can possibly be changed. That choice would change the productive structure and the corresponding quantities of the production factors. Note however: here and incidentally in the whole column a continuous growth or decrease of the system will not be considered.

Suppose that each of the techniques α and β must produce the same nett product QN, for instance QN = [3, 0.9]. Calculations show that the technique α requires 30 workers (as representatives of a unit of labour), and the technique β only 27.7. In other words, as soon as the technique α is replaced by the technique β, for instance because the corn has become expensive, then the producer must without delay lay off 2.28 workers3. So there is no gradual substitution of production factors, such as in the neoclassical paradigm. The technological changes are productive shocks. That is also apparent from the needed means of production. For the nett product, just mentioned, the technique α requires Q = [12, 3.1], and the technique β requires [15.8, 6.6]. So the change to β requires an ample doubling of the quantity of metal.

An interesting property of intertwined matrices is that it is unproblematic to display different techniques within a single matrix. Then the techniques coexist within the system, and can be used side by side. In the remainder of this column that representation will indeed be employed. This requires a concession, namely the transformation of the square matrices I and A into rectangular ones with dimensions 2×3. Now the vector a has the dimension 1×3. Both I, A and a are displayed in the figure 1. When subsequently the vector a is pasted underneath the matrix (I − A), then a 3×3 matrix is formed, which will be designated as B.

Picture of matrices I, A, a and B-1
Figure 1: matrices I, A and B-1, and the vector a

So henceforth in the formula 1a the matrices I and A will connect the plane (Qg, Qm) and the space (Q, Q, Qm). Here Q and Q represent the quantities of corn, that at a certain time are produced with respectively the technique α and β. The corn is identical in both cases, and only its production process differs. One has for the total produced quantity of corn the relation Qg = Q + Q. And the formula 1b is now an inner product between two vectors with each three elements. Incidentally, for the loyal reader this approach is not new, because it has already been applied in the column about the intertwined matrix for multi period optimization. However, there it is the industry, which can choose between two production methods, instead of the agriculture, like in the present case.

An important observation is that the set 1a-b can simply be rewritten into

(2)     Q = B-1 · H

In the formula 2 B-1 represents the inverse matrix of B. The vertical 3×1 vector H has QN as its upmost elements and L as its lowest. That is to say, H = [QgN, QmN, L]. In this case the labour L is distributed over the branch industry and the branch agriculture, and within the agriculture over both production methods. When QN and L are given, then all quantities Q can be calculated simply with the formula 2. So it is an extremely powerful formula.

The formula 2 allows to change the quantity of labour L in a continuous manner. The productive shocks have been eliminated. The reason is evidently, that now the production is a mixture of α and β. This has the consequence, that L is necessarily located between 27.72 and 30. For other values of L negative values will occur in Q, which is not reconcilable with economics. In the same way Qg and Qm remain constrained by minimal and maximal boundaries.

The relation between the vectors H and Q = [Q, Q, Qm] has an intuitive logic. For instance, when the nett product is fixed, and society wants to increase L, then this can only be achieved by extending the use of the technique α. For α has a low productivity, and requires a relatively large amount of labour. The immediate consequence is that Q must grow, and Q must shrink. In a similar manner the effect on Q of all kinds of changes in H can be studied.

So the matrix B-1 is extremely interesting, and it is displayed in the figure 1. In fact its elements are substitution coefficients. In the figure 1 this is emphasized by displaying above the matrix B-1 the quantities, that can be varied if desired (in other words, the vector H)4. Behind the matrix the quantities are displayed, that are influenced by the corresponding changes. The variation of a quantity in H causes shifts in the sizes (substitutions) of the elements of the production vector Q.

For instance, B-111 = -16.33 indicates, that the addition of an extra unit QgN will decrease the quantity Q by 16.33. For according as the product grows for a fixed L, the labour productivity must increase. Then more use must be made of the technique β, so that Q decreases. In the same manner for instance B-131 = 5.390 can be explained. A rising nett product for a fixed L requires more technique β, and thus more metal (Qm) as a means of production. An extra bale of corn in the nett product requires an expansion of the volume of metal with 5.390 tons. Etcetera.


Prices for the simultaneous application of two techniques

The mixing of production techniques, such as is assumed in the formula 2, is surprising. For in the column about the choice of the production technique it has been stated, that always one particular technique will yield the highest capital efficiency. The choice of the technique α or β depends on the wage level. Indeed a mixture of both techniques must result in a suboptimal capital efficiency. The producers have no incentive to maintain such a situation. In fact the formula 2 describes a transitional situation, where one technique in the system is gradually replaced by another one.

Picture of wage curves for technique mixing
Figure 2: wage curves for mixing f of α and β

But although the logic of economics dictates that the situation with a mixture is not stable, yet she reminds of the neoclassical paradigm. For the nett product QN represents the effective demand for products, and L is the demand on the labour market. A change in the market demand or in the demand for labour leads to an adaptation of the quantities of the production factors, according to the formula 2. However, contrary to the neoclassical belief the adaption lacks any logic. She is determined completely by the available production techniques.

The suboptimal character of the mixture becomes clear, when the system of product prices is considered5. For a detailed explanation of the price theory the reader is again referred to the column about the choice of technique. Also in the present situation with two simultaneous techniques the formulas of the theory can be applied in the usual manner, namely by defining the matrix A as the weighed sum of the separate techniques. The formula is:

(3)     aij = f × aijα + (1 − f) × aijβ

In the formula 3 f is the fraction of the labour L, that works with the technique α6. That is to say, 0 ≤ f ≤ 1.

Consider for instance four different mixtures of the techniques α and β, with f=1, f=0.66, f=0.22 and f=0. Suppose that the society wants under all circumstances to produce the existing nett product. When in the mixture f=1, with only the technique α, L=30 workers are employed, then for the other mixtures one has respectively L=29.5, 28.5 and 27.72. The last mixture, with f=0, is purely the technique β. One can think of a shrinking population, which is forced to transform its technique α to the more productive technique β. The figure 2 shows for these mixtures the corresponding wage curves7.

Picture of price curves for technique mixing
Figure 3: curves of pm/pg for mixtures f of α and β

It is immediately clear from the figure 2, that the mixtures f=1 (technique α) and f=0 (technique β) form the technology frontier. The other mixtures lie below this envelope. Only at the switching point of α and β (namely for r=0.024) all mixtures are on the technology frontier. There for a given wage level w/pg all techniques yield the same capital efficiency. The switching point is the pivot, as it were, that rotates the wage curve, according as f (and thus L) changes.

Two mutually opposing economic effects cause the tilting of the curve around r=0.024. On the one hand, the table 1 shows that the technique β has the highest productivity, so that she can guarantee for r=0 the highest wage level. On the other hand, this same table shows that the technique β requires a relatively large quantity of the means of production, so that a lot of interest must be paid. The remittance of interest (in the sense of a rent for the means of production) must be paid from the created nett product. According as the desired capital efficiency increases, the technique β will soon fail to provide for that interest.

At least as important for this column are the curves of the price ratio pm/pg as a function of the capital efficiency. For in the neoclassical paradigm the prices of the products equal their marginal utility. Their ratio indicates the value, that the society attaches to these products. Each mixture of α and β has her own price behaviour. The figure 3 illustrates that behaviour for f=1, 0.66, 0.22 and 08. Also for these curves r=0.024 is the pivot point. Apparently in general the valuation for metal increases for a rising capital efficiency. Only when tne technique β obtains a preponderant preference, the reverse behaviour occurs. Furthermore, note that in the figure the price ratio is never less than 6.34, namely with the technique β at r=0.178.

The figures 2 and 3 illustrate the balancing influence of the market. The techniques α and β come with their own price systems. However, as soon as they occur in a mixture, the market imposes a uniform price of the labour factors and of the end products. Nevertheless, the prices remain in a perpetual movement, as long as the mixture of techniques changes, for instance during a falling employment L. In the next paragraph the economic tendencies will again be discussed.


The choice of the technique by means of optimization

Several previous columns pay attention to optimization methods as a means for chosing the best mixture of techniques. In the capitalist system with its private production the application of optimization is mainly limited to the micro level, in the enterprises. But in the former Leninist planning economies this approach was also popular for macro-economic applications.

For the sake of completeness here the optimization problem is formulated again, though it has already been discussed in the related column about price formation. The solution employs linear programming (LP). The LP problem is expressed as:

(4a)     maximaliseer Z = p · (I − A) · Q onder de voorwaarden
(4b)     (I − A) · QQN
(4c)     a · Q ≤ L
(4d)     Q ≥ 0

In this column the properties of the set 4a-d will not be discussed again. It suffices to stress the social significance of the target function (or, more convenient in the present examples, Z'= Z/pg). The weighing factors p, which are usually equated to the market prices, are leading in the choice of the economic development. It is obvious that the neoclassical paradigm attaches importance to the influences of the market. Here the reader will perceive a problem. For the assumption of partial markets, where the interactions between the markets are ignored, does not hold.

When for instance the production factor L varies, then this will have immediate effects on the weighing factors p. In other words, in fact the weighing factors must not be the present market prices, but the market prices which are in force after the structural change. This introduces a severe complication in the optimization process, because the future market demand is a large unknown9.

On the other hand, suppose that the optimization occurs under the assumption of a constant pm/pg. Comsider the case where L and thus f decreases slowly with the advancement of time. Then the figure 3 shows nicely what will happen. The curve of the price ratios will rotate clockwise around r=0.024. Therefore in the domain r>0.024 the capital efficiency will rise. This is logical. The production transforms gradually to the technique β. And for r>0.024 this means a lower wage level at an identical efficiency. When thus in this development the nett product QN is kept fixed, then there is more room for an increased capital efficiency.

In this way the LP problem is placed in an interesting context, which was lacking in the previous columns about optimization. For the use of a fixed target function implies, that the optimization preserves neither the actual wage level nor the efficiency. In this paragraph this theme will be elaborated further by means of simple examples. It will be notably attempted to further the insights with regard to the so-called shadow prices. Shadow prices express the valuation for scarce products and resources, and therefore they are a neoclassical phenomenon. In all following examples the starting point is a fixed nett product QN = [3, 0.9].


Shadow prices as market prices

The preceding paragraph has shown that shadow prices do not really depend on the production costs. This is a well-known phenomenon13. Their greatest strength is the information about the most productive use of the available scarce products and resources. At the time the Soviet economist V.V. Novozhilov (in the German language W.W. Nowoshilow14) has pleaded in favour of the introduction of shadow prics as the common price system15. Then prices are the rent, which is due to the scarce resources. Novozhilov wants to calculate the actually expended costs by a procedure, that scales up the shadow prices. Then the total yield must equal the actually expended total amount of labour. In other words, his price system leads to a redistribution of the produced total value.

Novozhilov did not succeed in testing his ideas in practice, because several objections can be made16. The distribution function of the price becomes too important, and the costs are disregarded. The shadow prices depend very much on the "voluntary" choice of the target function. This can impede the technological progress. For outdated production processes could remain in service, simply because they contribute to the realization of the goal. There are no longer any incentives for the technological progress as a value in itself.

There is even the possible occurrence of moral hazard. The enterprises gain by making their products scarce, because this raises the price. Moreover there are ethical objections, because the proposal of Novozhilov violates the labour theory of value (LTV). Both the neoricardian theory and the LTV assume that in principle anything will be produced, that satisfies a need. The idea of scarcity does not go well with these theories.

Besides, such a centrally planned price system clashes with the daily reality of the planning in the former Leninist states17. For in practice the producers themselves were to some extent responsible for the price setting. The whole process had subjective aspects, which are not accessible for a mathematical optimization. And the price on the world market also exerts influence. In addition, the plan economies had a dynamic character, which in the long run allowed to eliminate scarcity. For all these reasons the plan economies used the shadow prices merely as one of the many factors, which entered into the determination of the product prices.

Thus the lessons from the examples have been summarized once more. The shadow prices do not resemble the cost prices. They do not guarantee an optimal efficiency. And they fluctuate in an arbitrary manner in reaction to changes of the available resources. Partial markets and fixed price rations do not exist18.

  1. On the other hand, this column has at least some resemblance with the method, which at the time the famous economist P.A. Samuelson used in his analysis of the surrogate production function. Samuelson tried to construct a production function consisting of the technology frontier of a multitude of linear wage curves. The resemblance is here that each "wage line" represents a technique, which shares just one point with the technology frontier. For all other efficiencies she is suboptimal. However, your columnist must admit, that his knowledge of the surrogate production function is insufficiently solid for a profound discussion. (back)
  2. The neoricardian paradigm offers an excellent opportunity for the creation of a micro-cosmos. There lots of amazing phenomena occur, but in the end the economic rationality always prevails. After some time spent in this world of phantasy, the word "model" becomes truly meaningful. (back)
  3. Here it becomes apparent why the technique β has a higher labour productivity than α. She adds per worker a larger quantity to the nett product. Even when this is transformed into value, the added value for β will still be higher. (back)
  4. The formula 2 may suggest that it is confusing to draw the elements of H above the matrix B-1. The idea is that the first column of the matrix is multiplied by QgN, the second by QmN, and the third by L. In the same way the first row represents the shifts, that influence the size of Q. The second row shows the shifts, that influenc eth size of Q. And the third row describes the shifts in the size of Qm. (back)
  5. Note that in the column about the multi-period optimization the price system is not addressed. In the plan economy of the Leninist states the prices were fixed in an artificial and rather ad hoc manner. (back)
  6. This does not say anything about the distribution of labour over the agriculture and the industry. For first some nett product must yet be chosen in order to completely fix the production structure. (back)
  7. The mathematical formulas for the wage curves are respectively w30.0/pg = (0.287 − 0.879×r + 0.384×r2) / (1 − 1.58×r), w29.5/pg = (0.293 − 1.03×r + 0.343×r2) / (1 − 1.32×r), w28.5/pg = (0.0.306 − 1.42×r + 0.242×r2) / (1 − 0.649×r), and w27.72/pg = (0.321 − 1.83×r + 0.134×r2) / (1 + 0.0669×r). The reader will observe, that calculations abound. (back)
  8. And here the mathematical formulas for the price ratios pm/pg at f=1, 0.66, 0.22 and 0 are respectively (6.25 + 1.34×r) / (1 − 1.58×r), (6.30 + 0.921×r) / (1 − 1.01×r), (6.42 + 0.0865×r) / (1 − 0.649×r), and (6.56 − 0.803×r) / (1 + 0.0669×r). Note how for f=0 the character of the ratio changes. For in this case she turns out to fall for a rising efficiency. On the other hand, for the three other cases she rises. (back)
  9. The exception which confirmts the rule is r=0.024. There the price ratio remains the same, irrespective of the chosen technique. (back)
  10. In fact any value in the interval [27.72, 30] can be chosen as the the start value of L. The only difference is the weighing factor, which changes each time. Your columnist has preferred to transform the LP problem into a simpler form worden gekozen. Define Q0 = (1 − A)-1 · QN, and L0 = a·Q0. Next define Q' = QQ0 en L' = L−L0. Then the set 1a-b is transformed into the set (I − A) · Q' ≥ 0 and a·Q' ≤ L'. In the studied case one has L' = ΔL = 1. This transformation has the charm of pushing the area of allowed Q'-values against the origin. Now the target function is Z'= p · (I−A) · Q' /pg. In this LP problem the elements of Q' can in principle be both positive or negative, so that they are unconfined. However, since the situation with a fixed QN is the starting point, only positive quantities Q' can be added. It is not possible to draw from the nett product. (back)
  11. See p.419 and further in the book Quantitative analysis for management (1997, Prentice Hall International) by B. Render and R.M. Stair. (back)
  12. The first three simplex tableaux are similar, irrespective of the extra requirements of the formulas 5 and 6. The formula 5 leads to an fourth and fifth simplex tableau. Also the formula 6 leads to a fourth and fifth simplex tableau. (back)
  13. See p.197 and further in Vorlesungen zur Theorie der Reproduktion (1988, Metropolis-Verlag) by L.L. Pasinetti. (back)
  14. This reminds of an amusing joke. When the answer is "Nine-W", what was the question? The question was: "Hey Fritz. Do you spell Wagner with a V?". (back)
  15. See p.80 and further in the book Grundfragen der sozialistischen Preistheorie (1977, Verlag Die Wirtschaft), published by a collective of authors under the direction of K. Ambrée, H. Mann and F. Matho. Matho has discussed the proposal before, on p.340 and further in Ökonomische Gesetze im gesellschaftlichen System des Sozialismus (1969, Dietz Verlag). Both books have been obtained from the enormous collection of the Berlin second-hand bookshop Helle Panke. (back)
  16. See p.81 and further in Grundfragen der sozialistischen Preistheorie. (back)
  17. This argument is found on p.345 in Ökonomische Gesetze im gesellschaftlichen System des Sozialismus. (back)
  18. It goes without saying that also Robert Vienneau discusses in his weblog optimizations, that can result in a mixture of techniques. He shows in a column, how a kind of production functions can be constructed. (back)